We are now seeing a corporate
takeover of dairy production, which is the last bastion of full-time,
independent family farms in animal agriculture.
In an April 2018 blog
post, Farm Aid noted that, since 1970, the number of American
dairy farmers has dropped by more than 93%, from more than 640,000 to
about 40,000 today.
The post goes on: “In an industry
dominated by corporate interests, family farms are constantly at risk
of going under. A consistent, severe slump in milk prices in recent
years has pushed many dairy farm businesses beyond the point of
survival. In the last year, there’s been a 3% drop in the number of
dairy farms, with the future of those remaining increasingly
uncertain.”
There has been little cause for
hope over the year since this Farm Aid blog post and little hope
for a significant improvement in prices for at least a year in the
future. Considering this stark situation, independent dairy farmers
would do well to review how the corporate takeover of other sectors
of animal agriculture has come about.
Poultry was the first to fall under
corporate control, followed by beef, then pork, and now dairy. The
corporatization of each sector has been a bit different, but all have
followed the same basic pattern. We now see that pattern unfolding in
dairy production.
I am more familiar with the
corporate takeover of the pork industry than that of poultry or beef.
It happened during the 1990s, while I was still an active faculty
member of the University of Missouri. Reluctantly, I became involved
in the controversy surrounding corporate takeover of hog production.
By then, the entire poultry industry was already vertically
integrated, which means a few large corporations controlled all
phases of production from breeding stock to retail-ready poultry
products. Cattle feeding had moved from small on-farm feedlots into
large corporate feedlots holding tens of thousands of animals. The
remaining small feedlots where farmers and ranchers fed out their own
calves were few. The longer production process for beef has made it
more difficult for corporations to control the cow-calf and stocker
phases of production, but they keep trying.
The production process for pork was
longer than for poultry but short enough to allow corporate control
of the entire process—from breeding stock to finished product.
Vertical integration of the pork industry had been limited by
persistent disease problems in the larger confinement hog feeding
operations. However, when routine feeding of antibiotics became a
common practice, a major obstacle to a corporate takeover of pork
production was removed. The remaining corporate challenge was to
displace independent hog farmers, many of whom were very efficient
producers.
During the 1990s, the University of
Missouri operated a mail-in records program for Missouri farmers.
Producers would mail copies of their purchases and sales records,
which the university used to prepare financial statements that
included their production costs and their profits. Each participant
would be provided with summaries of financial results for similar
producers so they could compare their performance with
others—benchmarking. We had enough records for farmers who
specialized in hog production to provide farmers with average
production costs for the most efficient and least efficient as well
the average efficiency of hog producers in the program. We also
had accurate information regarding costs of production in the large
corporate affiliated feeding operations that were trying to gain a
foothold in the state at the time.
The mail-in records indicated that
the large corporate feeding operations would likely be more efficient
than the least efficient one-third to one-half of existing Missouri
hog producers. However, the corporate operations were likely to be
less efficient than the most efficient one-third to one-half of
existing hog producers. In other words, any production-cost advantage
enjoyed by the large corporate operations would be small compared to
the production costs of the average Missouri hog producer.
However, by being vertically integrated in pork processing and
distribution as well as hog production, the large corporate
operations were ultimately able to drive even the most efficient
independent hog producers out of business.
Under political pressure from the
pork industry, Missouri’s anti-corporate farming law was changed to
allow a large corporate pork operation to locate in north Missouri.
During the mid-1990s, Premium Standard Farms built a large slaughter
plant and feed mill and quickly acquired 80,000 sows expecting to
produce more than 1.5 million slaughter hogs a year. Similar large
corporate operations had begun earlier in North Carolina and were
expanding rapidly during times of profitable hog prices. Most of the
corporate hogs in North Carolina were produced under comprehensive
contracts that gave the corporation virtually complete control over
production. It was obvious this rapid expansion in hog numbers
eventually would depress hog prices to unprofitable levels for most
existing producers.
The key to the corporate takeover
was that they could easily outlast the least efficient one-third of
independent producers during the inevitable depression in hog prices
resulting from their expansion in production. But the corporate
operations didn’t even need to be more efficient than the average
independent producer. The corporations were involved in pork
processing and slaughter as well as production. The packers lowered
wholesale pork prices enough to allow the pork from hogs under their
control to clear the market, but only enough to leave prices
seriously depressed in markets where independent producers were
forced to sell. Any corporate losses on their owned or contract hogs
were largely offset by wider margins of profit for hogs purchased
from independent producers. Independent producers were not only
forced to sell at large losses, some couldn’t find markets at any
price. During the late 1990s, market prices for hogs dropped to a low
of $8 per hundred pounds, while average costs of production were more
than $40 per hundred pounds.
Enough independent producers were
eventually forced out of business to allow hog prices to return to
more reasonable levels. However, as the less efficient producers were
forced out of business, or became corporate contract producers to
survive, an increasing share of total hog production came under
corporate control. Eventually, even the most efficient independent
producers couldn’t survive these market conditions. Even the
vertically integrated corporations lost money at times during the
takeover, and some were forced out of business as they competed for
market share and control. The surviving corporations succeeded in
taking over virtually complete control of the hog industry—from hog
genetics to finished pork products.
The takeover process for pork was
similar in many respects to earlier experiences with poultry and
beef. The least efficient independent producers are the first to be
forced out of business by more efficient corporate producers. Once
the corporations gain control of a significant share of the total
market, they can begin to manipulate market prices available to
remaining independent producers. During times of surplus, the
corporations limit reductions in wholesale prices in order to depress
and hold market prices for independent producers to unprofitable
levels long enough to force the survivors out of business. Obviously,
agri-food corporations would not be able to manipulate prices or
marketing margins in this way if markets were actually competitive.
However, corporate antitrust laws have not been seriously enforced in
the U.S. since the early 1900s.
Unfortunately, this is the harsh
reality now confronting smaller independent dairy producers. The
unbridled expansion of large confinement dairy operations has
increased total production and depressed milk prices to unprofitable
levels for most independent producers. Weaker consumer demand for
dairy products has magnified the depression. The least efficient
independent producers have already been forced out of business by
previous expansion in production and the large corporate dairy
operations are continuing to expand. The remaining independent dairy
farmers are now at risk.
The government has long been
involved in pricing of milk, which makes the milk market somewhat
different than that for other animal products. In addition,
cooperatives are among the largest corporate processors of milk but
are acting more like corporations than cooperatives. It remains to be
seen whether the large corporate dairy operations have gained
sufficient market power to drive out the most efficient independent
dairy producers. Regardless, the remaining independent dairy farmers
can’t afford to ignore the lessons learned from the corporatization
of poultry, beef, and pork.
>> The article above was written by John Ikred, and is reprinted from In These Times.
No comments:
Post a Comment