On Monday, March 9, the Dow Jones
futures market immediately dropped 1800 points. This triggered an
automatic “circuit breaker” in the market, in which trade was
halted for 15 minutes. After the trading curb ended, futures
contracts continued to fall until the total point losses were around
2000 points, or a loss of 7.8 percent. This was preceded by a longer,
slower decline beginning in February, when the Dow Jones Industrial
Average (DJIA) had reached a peak of 29,000 and declined 14 percent
to 25,000 at the same time in March.
The fall in the American stock
market was mirrored in international markets as well: the Brazilian
IBOVESPA index fund lost 12%; the Chinese CSI 300 Index fell by 3%,
the Hong Kong Hang Seng index fell by 4.2%, and the Japanese Nikkei
225 fell by 5.1%. In Asian markets specifically, stocks have been
declining since December, signaling an end to the boom in financial
capital prices.
The market collapse comes in the
context of the escalation of two major events: the escalation of the
COVID-19 coronavirus outbreak into a global pandemic, and an oil
price war between oil-producing nations that has forced prices of
crude oil down to around $35 per barrel. In this article, I’ll
place these two short-term crises into the context of longer-term
crises of production in the United States and Asia.
Spread of coronavirus and
its economic impacts
I won’t spend too much time on
the virus itself, but it helps to have a little context on how
quickly the disease spread. COVID-19 disease was first identified in
Wuhan, China, in late December 2019. It initially presented itself s
a cluster of pneumonia cases of unknown cause. The disease is
characterized by a symptom onset time of between two and 14 days, and
the ability to transmit an infection before any symptoms are
displayed. The initial spread of the virus was facilitated by the
Chinese New Year, spreading symptomatic and asymptomatic carriers
throughout both the country and the world. By Jan. 20, over 6000
people had developed symptoms, while the number of asymptomatic
carriers remains unknown.
The Chinese government responded
with relatively draconian but effective measures, quarantining
several cities in Hubei province and enforcing social distancing,
resulting in an eventual decline in newly reported cases by late
February. By this time, however, new cases had begun to explode in
Italy, Iran, and South Korea. Northern Italy in particular has been
hit particularly hard; the province of Lombardy is under quarantine,
and reports are that hospitals are almost completely overwhelmed.
One of the first-order effects of
the pandemic is on global supply chains for manufactured goods,
especially electronics. Since these supply chains are centered on
largely Chinese manufacturing, the imposition of quarantine resulted
in large-scale disruption to the production of manufactured goods.
The economic meaning is that once available stocks have been shipped,
we will begin to see shortages and price increases for certain
manufactured goods, especially electronics. This is sort of the
common-sense supply-side story.
There’s also a common-sense
demand-side story as well. The response by governments to the
pandemic will take the form of something of a continuum of two
strategies: either (1) do nothing, and rely on individual measures
like social distancing or self-quarantine, or (2) take extremely,
shall we say, proactive steps
to halt the spread of the virus. In either case, there will be a
reduction in the amount of expenditure on the one hand of wage
goods—because at the very least, the service sector will experience
a major contraction. The slow down in service work will get worse as
public health systems become overloaded. In countries with weak
worker protections as well as non-existent public health
institutions, such as the United States, this will also result in
large numbers of people losing their jobs and their homes.
On the other hand, the price of
capital goods will begin to fall as well, because underlying every
demand crisis is a profitability crisis. This is a very important
point, because the profitability crisis gives us the difference
between “a public health catastrophe” and “a public health
catastrophe that precipitates a global recession.”
Underlying crisis
Over the past decade, stock prices
have grown enormously, much faster than dividends. The reason for
this is investment capital flowing to its most profitable use, that
is to say, the greatest return on investment. For the purpose of this
article, we can consider financial instruments, in general, as
futures contracts.
We purchase today a contract
entitling us to a future return. We can then turn around and sell
this contract based on the fact of that future, unrealized return and
then make a profit. So financial positions based on future unrealized
gains are used to cover the positions of other financial
positions based on future gains. This can actually go on for quite
some time, as seen by the long boom in financial asset prices seen
after 2008.
However, this requires two things:
the first is cheap credit. We can think of the interest rate as a
sort of tool to discipline the financial market. If the interest rate
I need to pay is 8% every year, then I’d better make sure that I am
generating at least that much in profit. In fact, the interest rate
has remained below 2% for almost the entirety of the past decade.
This indicates that there are still very few productive avenues for
investment in the real economy.
The second thing that is required
is stability. The game of “financialization” can go on for quite
a long time until credit-lubricated demand for both consumer goods
and investment goods falters. The world is currently experiencing a
shock to both from the coronavirus. Once demand collapses in a few
key industries, such as airline travel, this usually leads to a chain
reaction as financial profits based on future real returns
fail to materialize.
Shocks and spills: The
story of oil
The oil price shock comes at the
tailwinds of several global trends that preceded the current crisis
by a few years. The first of these is falling demand for oil
globally; some of which is due to the small but growing switch to
renewable energy worldwide. A larger factor is the long-term decline
in Asian manufacturing. Even before the coronavirus, Chinese growth
in GDP fell to its lowest point in 2019. The decision by
oil-exporting nations not to cut production seems to be a decision to
increase revenue by increasing output and putting the more expensive
American and Canadian shale oil and gas producers out of business.
Finally, the anticipated drop in demand due to the pandemic put
pressure on primarily oil-exporting nations to try and cut production
further in order to sustain prices. These talks failed, and the
result is the collapse of collaboration between OPEC and Russian oil
interests.
The fall in oil prices is causing
financial contagion in the real sector through two channels. The
first is the channel that I outlined above: investors that are
heavily invested in oil priced their futures contracts in with the
expectation of a given return that is now impossible given the
dramatic fall in the price of oil. Another, largely unexplored,
channel is the fact that American-Canadian shale oil is both
extremely unprofitable and extremely debt-laden.
We know from Marx 101 that as the
organic composition* of capital in an industry rises, the rate of
profit tends to fall. Shale extraction, often accomplished by
fracking, is one of the most capital-intensive industries there is.
However, output from these projects declines much faster than anyone
anticipated, and returns in the industry are low even when the price
of oil is high. The industry has attracted enormous levels of capital
investment to the tune of $200 billion of debt just in 2015, and
likely much higher in 2019. A collapse in the shale industry would
cause reciprocal falls in the prices of capital goods in the United
States and worldwide.
Which way forward?
If the response is left in the
hands of capital, in the short term, a nasty recession is all but
assured, given the drastic falls in manufacturing output in the Asian
countries over the past several months. In addition to this, Western
countries may be facing down the barrel of a public health
catastrophe, given the unpreparedness of governments here and
elsewhere in responding to the coronavirus.
In the long run, because of
persistently weak consumer and investment demand, both the European
Central Bank (ECB) and the Federal Reserve have kept interest rates
at historically low levels. Despite this, private capital is
undertaking a “flight to safety,” meaning that capital is flowing
into U.S. bonds at historically low rates—so low that, after
accounting for 30 years of inflation, an investor is guaranteed
to lose money.
In other words, the outlook for the profitability of investment is so
bad, they would rather hand it to the U.S. government at a modest
loss than to risk it by putting it into the circuit of production.
This means that monetary policy, either through quantitative easing
or interest-rate reductions, which has been the primary tool of
recession-prevention in past years, will be completely ineffective.
There is no way for capital to
“manage” itself out of this crisis. The solution it puts forward
will be to cut its losses as much as possible and put the rest on the
backs of the working class. Instead of inaction, repression, and
austerity, workers have the opportunity to demand unlimited sick time
at full pay and immediate mobilization of medical workers to address
the reality of the pandemic. Already, organized labor has been coming
together to make these demands on citywide bases, such as in Chicago.
The effort must be expanded and coordinated on a national scale.
So too must the demands take into
consideration the reality of the coming recession. To stop the
economic downfall from an oil war, trade unions, especially those
involved with industries like pipeline construction, must demand an
immediate transition to 100% clean, renewable energy within the next
five years. In response to the already-begun recession, the solution
involves, on the one hand, public ownership of housing to stave off a
homelessness crisis, and on the other, the expropriation of all
finance capital, whose only response to death and destruction is to
re-inflate the burst bubble. Both actions must be taken without
compensation for either the big landlords or the big banks.
The only social force that is
capable of making such demands, either rhetorically or in action, is
the working class. The corona outbreak proves the burning need for a
labor party and a fighting union movement that can win the necessary
solutions to the problems forced on us by the bosses.
>> The article above was
written by Ahmed Khan.
*The Marxist Internet Archive
defines the organic composition of capital as “the ratio of the
value of the materials and fixed costs (constant capital) embodied in
production of a commodity to the value of the labour-power (variable
capital) used in making it.”
Photo: Mark Lennihan / AP
1 comment:
Post a Comment